Output by workers grows with increases in population and in productivity. Consumption by non-workers grows only with increases in their population. A little algebra shows that if the growth rate for productivity is equal to the difference in the growth rates in population, then the system remains in balance, even the the ratio of workers to non-workers is declining. Assuming equality in those rates, everyone's standard of living (per-capita amount of goods and services) remains exactly the same, as the increases due to productivity exactly offset the higher growth rate of the non-workers. If productivity growth is higher, then everyone's standard of living can increase. This has certainly been the case with the US Social Security system. The ratio of workers to retirees has fallen from about eight in 1956 to a little over three in 2009, but everyone's standard of living has improved.
Social Security critics contend that having the worker to retiree ratio decrease from three to two will be disastrous, even though the fall from eight to three was not. Either they are ignoring increases in worker productivity, or they are implicitly stating that productivity can't keep pace with the change in populations. The former is an error in analysis, as productivity has been the key factor to date. The latter is a point of legitimate concern, as I will discuss in just a moment. Before doing that, though, a small digression...
All of the formal models that show a Social Security “crisis” in 2040 or 2050 – the one used by the SS trustees, the one used by the Congressional Budget Office, the one used by the Cato Institute – show that the crisis is not the result of benefit growth relative to GDP, but because of revenue shortfalls relative to GDP. The shortfalls occur because the GDP growth due to increases in productivity largely go to workers earning more than the cap on wages subject to the SS tax. In short, the models forecast that the old saw that “a rising tide lifts all boats” will not be true, and that the tide is going to rise over at the end of the marina with the big yachts, but not at the end with the little rowboats. Such a trend is likely, IMO, to result in significant societal problems well before 2040. But that's a topic for another day...
Lots of people have put together some version of the graph shown here. This particular one plots, for a number of countries, the log of per-capita income on the vertical axis and the log of per-capita energy consumption on the horizontal. The size of the circle represents the population of the country. The line is a least-squares best fit to the data points, not weighted by population. The correlation between productivity and energy consumption is clear. The direction of the causal arrow is unclear; do countries use more energy because they are richer (eg, jet skis for leisure), or are they richer because they use more energy (eg, backhoes instead of shovels)?
From its beginnings with Solow, economic growth theory has struggled to account for the growth that has actually occurred in the developed countries. Solow found that about 65% of the actual growth had to be attributed to factors other than labor and capital. Lots of different additions to the basic theory have been suggested, such as the concept of “human capital,” resulting in increasingly complex models. Ayres and Warr have taken a different approach [3], and assumed that the underlying problem was the model of production. A production function with a term for external energy sources fits the actual history in both the US and the UK quite well. Their work provides a theoretical basis for a causal link from energy use to productivity. Which brings us back to the subject of pensions. The sustainability of our pension systems requires that productivity increase sufficiently to offset the difference in the growth rates of worker and non-worker populations. Productivity increases require increased energy consumption (less increases in energy efficiency). Can energy use increase at the required pace, for say the next 30 years? The opinions on that question are all over the map. To select a few: James Kunstler says not just no, but hell no; Amory Lovins says probably yes, because efficiency can be improved so much; and the Energy Information Agency just says yes. I am inclined to say “Yes, in the long run,” but there's going to be an ugly transition period.
- John Eatwell, “The Anatomy of the Pensions 'Crisis'”.
- In Eatwell's model, “public” and “private” pensions are fundamentally the same except for the financial mechanism for making the transfer. In a public pension, such as the US Social Security program, the transfer is implemented in the form of taxes on workers and government payments to non-workers. In a private system, the transfer is implemented in the form of sales of assets (primarily financial instruments such as stocks and bonds) by non-workers to workers. Both mechanisms have advantages and disadvantages, but in both it is clear that non-workers receive their pension only through the cooperation of the workers. If the workers don't pay their taxes in a public system, the non-workers have a problem. If the workers don't buy the securities from the non-workers in a private system, the non-workers have exactly the same problem.
- Robert U. Ayres and Benjamin Warr, “Accounting for Growth: The Role of Physical Work”.